Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

Repealing pension reform would be dangerous

The pension reform has been criticised for being poorly prepared and poorly negotiated. So be it. However, repealing it would be very financially dangerous given the fragility of our public finances and the absolute need to redress them. Any sign of a worsening situation could trigger a serious French debt financing crisis. Therefore, the repeal of this reform would be understood by savers and the markets as irresponsible. Public pension spending on GDP will already represent 14.4% in 2022 compared to 11.9% in the eurozone.

But the repeal would also be very unfavourable for the French economically (for households or businesses) and ultimately for jobs and purchasing power. The only possible ways to ensure the balance of pay-as-you-go pension schemes are to lower the level of pensions, which is obviously good neither for retirees nor for the economy. To increase social contributions, through being paid by employees, thus causing a loss of purchasing power and downward pressure on demand. Or paid by businesses, knowing that these social contributions on GDP are already 50% higher in France than in Germany and 30% higher than in the euro zone on average, which ultimately amounts to less competitiveness, fewer jobs and downward pressure on wages. Finally, the third and final solution is to adjust the length of working life according to demographic changes.

Age measures (retirement age or, better, number of annuities) adjusted of course according to the arduousness of each person’s work, are the only ones capable of reconciling the interests of current or future retirees and the search for the best growth potential for the economy, employment and purchasing power. All the more so since even today many companies cannot grow as much as they could due to a lack of skilled or unskilled labor. A reminder: in France, we had 4 contributors for 1 retiree in 1960. In 2010, there were only 1.8 contributors for 1 retiree and it will be 1.2 in 2050. At the same time, in 1958, life expectancy at retirement age was 15.6 years for women and 12.5 years for men. In 2020, it is 26.9 years and 22.4 years respectively. While the retirement age is lower today than in 1958. Life expectancy in good health after retirement has also increased considerably. In France, only around 30% of people aged 60 to 64 work, while in other eurozone countries, almost 50% do so. 57% in Germany and 68% in Sweden! All neighbouring countries have indeed raised the retirement age (65 to 67 years) for the same reasons and out of realism. As a result, we must also finally wake up to the reality principle, so that our pay-as-you-go pension scheme is not endangered by the inability to finance it. This reform even if insufficient, is a step in the right direction. It is always possible to adjust it a little, but being careful not to open Pandora’s box…

Finally, two thoughts. First of all, work is not only economically necessary, it is also most often a means of integration, socialisation and self-fulfilment. Let us therefore facilitate the work of those over 60 and encourage companies to keep them, or even hire them. The second: work is not to be shared because it would be in finite quantity. It is a static and erroneous view of the economy that leads to thinking this way. Work creates work in a dynamic where supply and demand feed each other. All empirical results confirm this.

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone Global economy Uncategorized

The reasoning errors of those who want to increase compulsory contributions.

We know that the rate of compulsory contributions in France is one of the highest of the 38 OECD countries and much higher than the average of those countries. We are less aware that after redistribution, income inequalities in France, whether measured by the Gini index, by the ratio between the income of the wealthiest 10% and that of the least wealthy 10% or by the relative poverty rate, have not changed or have barely changed over the past 20 years, contrary to what some say. And that they are among the lowest in Europe and in the world.

In France, redistribution is very high, reducing the ratio between the income before redistribution of the wealthiest 10% and that of the least well-off 10% from 20 to 9. And from 20 to 3 by adding the effect of public services paid more by the wealthiest due to the high progressivity of taxes. 85% of people among the poorest 30% thus receive more in terms of public services than they pay, compared to 57% for all people in France (INSEE study of 2023 on extended redistribution). Ignoring this when building economic programs is obviously a source of inadequate proposals and therefore dangerous for the economy and ultimately for the least well-off. Obviously, the same reasoning is not tenable for the United States for example, where income inequality is much higher and has increased significantly over the past 20 years.

Another fundamental point is seriously ignored by certain programs. The economy and the social spheres are not static. They are dynamics whose effects are difficult to isolate from each other and whose interactions can cause favorable or catastrophic developments, even contrary to the desired goals.

If, compulsory contributions in France which are already on the European and OECD podium, are increased further, they will have a negative effect on employment – by reducing the competitiveness of companies, the dynamics of entrepreneurship, the incentive to work, etc. – as well as on growth. However, employment and growth are the main factors in the fight against poverty and in the development of the standard of living. Since 2000, France’s GDP per capita has declined in relative terms in Europe.

Similarly, supply and demand should not be considered separately. France already has a very large trade deficit and a current deficit that demonstrate its insufficient competitiveness. Its financial dependence on the rest of the world is thus constantly increasing. Artificially increasing demand would only further aggravate the external deficit. The development of the economy requires that demand be firm, but it also requires the simultaneous development of a competitive supply, which will also increase demand, particularly through the development of employment. Demand cannot be sustained for long through ever-increasing public spending, which ends up

leading to unsustainable debt. Nor can it be sustained by financing this spending through an incessant increase in contributions that end up reducing supply and jobs. The right way to fight against poverty and for purchasing power is therefore certainly not to further increase taxes and contributions, which are already very high, nor public spending (which in the long term is not positively correlated with growth), but to promote technological and green innovation, social mobility to improve equality of opportunity and incentives to work, since many companies cannot grow due to a lack of human resources, etc. Let’s stop cherishing the causes that lead to the effects that we deplore!

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

Monetary policy cannot do everything

Today, inflation has returned for the long term. Central banks must counter it. But an excessive rise in interest rates can trigger a recession, a hard landing. It can be too strongly calibrated, if we think that the transitory component of current inflation will weaken in the near future. Supply constraints have already begun to ease over time, barring the consequences of an escalation in the war. But an excessively slow rise in interest rates would lead to an increase in indexation. Reacting late, once inflation expectations are no longer anchored at a low level, would cost much more. Making deep recessions inevitable.

Interest rates too low for too long have globally led to very high debt ratios and bubbles in both equities and property. Rates must therefore be raised and quantitative easing policies gradually come to an end. But central banks are facing the risk of bursting bubbles, with impacts on growth, and the risk of insolvency for the most indebted companies and governments. This situation is therefore problematic for central banks, which must be very determined and very cautious. As a result, they have begun the normalisation of their policy and will go as far as its neutralisation. Including through a gradual exit from quantitative easing. But once this stage is reached, they will act according to the circumstances. If growth weakens sharply, if markets fall substantially, they will warn. The state of wage and price indexation, and therefore of the level of “structural” inflation, will then be scrutinised, in order to question the opportunity or danger of positioning interest rates above the neutral rate. If the inflationary regime were to strengthen further, they would very likely tighten their policy, both by raising their interest rates above the potential growth rate, and increasing quantitative tightening.

In this context, they will conduct monetary policies that are closely linked to data as they arise. While avoiding being dominated by fiscal issues and financial markets.

Meanwhile, governments have no choice but to have a credible medium-term solvency trajectory. An overly strict fiscal policy would destroy growth, but doing nothing when the level of indebtedness is high would undermine their credibility, which would be a very high risk in the short term.  They therefore need to put in place a policy of managing public finances without austerity, but which in reality is an exit from support policies. The unexpected, brutal and temporary pandemic is indeed to be differentiated from a possible change in inflation regime.

In addition, the investments needed to increase potential growth or green growth must be financed. However, this financing must be secured by more rational and efficient management of public spending, as well as by structural reforms. The latter are necessary to increase potential growth, i.e. sooner or later for a better ratio of public debt to GDP. They are also a means of combating inflation, the origin of which in Europe is more linked to a supply shock. And when the labour supply is very insufficient, job shortages can be alleviated by the reform of the labour market and the unemployment system, as by pension reform. In France, the employment rate of people over sixty is much lower than that of the rest of the eurozone.

The road is narrow. The essential fight against inflation, without too many economic and financial difficulties, requires a good combination of monetary policy and structural policies. Monetary policy can do a lot, but it cannot do everything on its own.

Categories
Conjoncture Economical policy Euro zone

“Inflation, interest rates and debt”

Updated on 21/10/2022

Categories
Euro zone Global economy

Inflation, interest rates and debts: an explosive cocktail

Should central banks have to finance public deficits linked to reindustrialisation, climate change or rearmament over the very long term, as opposed to the “we’ll do whatever it takes” approach that only lasted as long as the pandemic did? Does the debt not matter, in that case? Trapped by too many contradictory objectives, extremely accommodative monetary policies would then be prolonged, with interest rates remaining well below the growth rate and central banks’ balance sheets continuing to swell. No way! This is a convenient idea, but it’s a recipe for a very painful future. So, central banks are taking a different path.

Before the war, because inflation was more than only transitory, central banks had to exit quantitative easing and raise their interest rates gradually. But because of very high global debt levels and high valuations on financial and real estate markets, they toughened their tone cautiously when a strong surge in inflation occurred due to the war in Ukraine. An inflation that gets out of hand through indexation, even if imperfect, of prices to prices and wages to prices would indeed be a source of many evils. It would de facto lead to a significant inequality in income trends in real terms, both between households and between companies, as the ability to pass on price rises would be far from equal. Wage negotiations would become very contentious; price signals between producers, distributors and consumers would be unstable; loan contracts would lead to a disruption in the way interest rates are set between lenders and borrowers. Stable and low inflation is indeed essential for confidence among market participants, and therefore for an efficient economy. Today, faced with the threat of stagflation, central banks are faced with an even more delicate dilemma.

They must not undermine this weakening growth, but they have no choice other than to react if they have any hope of combating the major risk of uncontrolled inflation. \Therefore, if and when central banks normalise their monetary policy, they will have to do so with a great deal of clarity for the sake of their credibility, but also with great caution. They will have to test the effects on the financial markets, including government debt, at each stage. The ECB has an additional challenge: the eurozone is made up of countries with very divergent economic situations. At the same time, governments will have to show a credible fiscal trajectory, by making investments that promote potential and greener growth, but also by protecting the poorest from inflation… Structural reforms will also be essential, and more than ever, to facilitate growth and to participate in the solvency path – we are talking in particular about that of pensions in France. This narrow path is the only one possible.

If central banks were to perpetuate ad libitum a policy of financing public deficits and maintaining excessively low interest rates, serious financial crises due to the bursting of increasingly uncontrollable bubbles would cascade, structurally damaging growth. Inflation would sky-rocket to the detriment of the weakest and damaging the overall efficiency of the economy. And, sooner or later, confidence in money itself could be called into question. The flight from money would eventually lead to the collapse of the economy and the social order. Historical examples bear witness to this. Monetary policies will therefore tighten and interest rates will rise. There is little time left for highly indebted agents, public or private, to prepare for this.

Categories
Economical policy Euro zone

The new debt equation in the next five years period

Should interest rates be lower than the growth rate for the long term, implying that debt is not important? This is not my thesis and I believe that central banks will initiate or continue a gradual increase in their rates. What will be the possible and relevant reactions for any government with a high level of debt?

Before the very recent war in Ukraine, growth was strong, even if it fell slightly in view of the slow return to a more normal growth rate after the 2021 rebound.  Monetary policy was therefore expected to be at least normalised, smoothly due to the high overall debt and highly valued financial and real estate markets, by gradually exiting the quantitative easing policy, as well as by cautiously raising interest rates.  This need for tightening came from the risk of overheating. But also from the risk of monetary policy being exhausted in the event of new (and there are always) future crises. Finally, from the development of bubbles due to interest rates that have been too low for too long compared to growth rates.

Then, several months ago, there was an upsurge in inflation. It was clear that part of this inflation was not transitory and that we were probably changing inflationary regime.  The Fed, then the ECB, were therefore prompted to accelerate their announcement of a gradual end to their net securities purchases on the markets.   They also said they would raise their rates a little faster than expected. For the same reasons as described above, however, the issue was still not to proceed too quickly in exiting their very accommodative policy. Moreover, the ECB had to deal with the more specific and difficult eurozone issue, due to the large imbalances between the countries of the South and the North.

At the same time, governments had, and still have, a need for investment for the development of new technologies, re-industrialisation (even partial) and the energy transition. There was therefore a conflict between, on the one hand, the objective of financial stability undermined by interest rates that have been too low for too long and now the fight against inflation and, on the other hand, the objective of financing the necessary new investments and the solvency of governments, or even private players, whose debt had increased sharply since 2000 for the private sector and since 2007 for the public sector, with in addition a significant increase in public debt due to the pandemic.

Hence, the raising of several voices in the eurozone. The first stating the need to change the common budgetary rules, by excluding investment budgets from the calculation of constraints on public deficits. This proposal is sometimes coupled with the idea that, under current circumstances, the level of public debt was of little importance, and that the central banks would continue to finance future deficits for a long time. Another voice showed a narrower path, but it seems to me much more credible, certainly explaining the need to change the eurozone’s common rules, which are dated and ineffective, but at the same time stressed the importance of the compromises to be found between the countries of the North and the South on these changes in rules so as to select as candidates for exclusion only investments that actually generate potential growth or facilitate the energy transition. All expenses not always resulting in more potential growth. And the improvement in growth potential not always requiring additional spending. It was also crucial, from this point of view, to agree on reasonable budgetary rules, preventing any “free rider” behaviour.

The spectre of stagflation

Today, the war situation has created the spectre of stagflation. Therefore of a slowdown in growth which will be at least 1% and inflation even stronger than expected before the start of the war. This will create an even more intense dilemma for central banks. However, if the very sharp upsurge in inflation were to lead to no reaction or a very weak reaction on their part, a major risk of an inflation spiral could arise. Today, the question of whether there will be a second round of inflation no longer arises. Many industrialists and large retailers are increasing their prices, otherwise they are no longer able to cope with rising costs. And many companies have begun to raise their wages. They cannot act otherwise, in order to retain their skills, as well as to be able to recruit. The upcoming wage negotiations will reinforce this phenomenon.

However, if inflation takes hold through price-to-price, wage-to-price and price-to-wage indexation, with slower growth, we will enter a potentially lasting stagflationary dynamic. When Volcker, then Fed Chairman, tried to exit a long stagflation, in 1979, he had to provoke a deep recession in order to break the indexation phenomena. Ignoring inflation would also be very dangerous in terms of inequality, because no one is equal, neither among employees nor among companies, in the face of the ability to pass on any price increases in their incomes. Moreover, there is a need to fear inflation that could be transformed into a system of hyperinflation, causing economic agents to lose their bearings. Stable and low inflation allows for viable wage agreements; reliable price catalogues between producers, distributors and consumers; loan agreements to set interest rates between borrowers and lenders based on shared inflation expectations. In short, stable and sufficiently low inflation is essential to confidence. However, it is necessary for an efficient economy. Monetary policy must therefore react in a timely manner. If it were not to do so, it would have to act later by taking much more risk. Central banks must remain credible.  By supporting growth, of course, but clearly by combating inflation. Uncontrolled inflation also undermines growth itself.

This path will be very narrow

This path will be very narrow.  The monetary tightening policy must therefore necessarily be very cautious, and therefore very gradual. As a result, this trajectory will also require governments to play their part. On the one hand, governments will have to make the aforementioned necessary investments, generators of potential growth and, on the other hand, reduce unnecessary expenditure or reallocate it usefully. France has had the highest public expenditure as a percentage of GDP in the eurozone for a long time, but in some areas this expenditure has, in recent decades, provided a quality that bears little relation to the level of expenditure incurred. The OECD’s many comparative measures testify to this on a regular basis. Thus, the effort must not be only financial. The essential investments can therefore only be made if the essential reforms are carried out. Such as the reform of retirement – which while reducing the public deficit – supports potential growth because it increases the population available for work, whereas currently France is one of the countries with the significantly lowest employment rate after the age of 60.

All in all, it is imperative that central banks neutralise, at least, but cautiously, their monetary policy, in order to combat too much inflation, as well as to avoid financial instability due to bubbles that would continue to develop. And, at the same time, it is essential that governments increase potential growth through investment and reform and ensure better control of spending. In order to give credible trajectories to their fiscal policy and ensure their solvency in a world where interest rates will be structurally rising.

On 16 March this year, the Fed increased its intervention rate by 25 cents and indicated that there would be numerous hikes in the future. The following day, the ECB, in turn, announced an end to its net securities purchases at the end of June and paved the way to subsequent rate hikes. Furthermore, if the ECB did not perform such a policy change, the euro would continue to depreciate against the dollar in particular, leading to even higher inflation, due to the rise in prices in euros of imported products. The trend therefore seems to be underway.

The idea of a “war economy”, war against climate change, war for re-industrialisation, as well as a military war, as begins to be mentioned here and there among some economists – if it led to the belief that debt was of no importance and that the central banks would be obliged to finance any new deficit thus allowing very sustainable spending without constraints – could lead to a disaster. This concept of war economy, as previously stated, inevitably leads to the idea of a very long period of time.  Unlike a “whatever it costs”, limited to the duration of the pandemic. However, this idea includes an unthinkable: money. Money is the foundation of the debt settlement system. Having confidence in money means having confidence in the effectiveness of the debt settlement system. Therefore, if ever the monetary constraint[1] were suspended for too long, then confidence in money could be called into question. And if we no longer had confidence in money, we could experience, not traditional inflation, but a flight from money. If the central banks were to never stop quantitative easing and endlessly keep rates too low relative to the growth rate, not only would there be regular serious financial explosions, but sooner or later this would also lead to a flight from money that would be dramatic. This would result in the disorganisation and collapse of the economy and society. Because money constitutes the social link. As Michel Aglietta says: “confidence in money is the alpha and omega of society”.


[1] Either the obligation to pay one’s debts or, more precisely, for governments and companies, to refinance them at maturity with lenders other than central banks.